South Africa: Constitutional Assembly Resources Support SAFLII

You are here:  SAFLII >> Databases >> South Africa: Constitutional Assembly Resources >> 1995 >> [1995] ZAConAsmRes 1655

| Noteup | LawCite

Voters' Representation [1995] ZAConAsmRes 1655 (3 July 1995)

 


3 July 1995

Voters' Representation


Enclosed please find my comments on Proportional and Constituency Representation for voters in Parliament and Regional Councils. My main idea is an effort to combine the merits of each method. The mechanics by which this is achieved may be better worked out by others, but I have given a proposal to start from.

J. G. Gie

PROPORTIONAL REPRESENTATION
AND
CONSTITUENCY REPRESENTATION


Both of the above methods of representation of voters in Parliament and Regional Councils have advantages and disadvantages. An effort should be made in the final Constitution to incorporate the better features of both methods.

Proportional representation has the great advantage that it reflects the numbers of voters in the whole country who support various parties, and give the truest idea of the broad opinions of the voters. It has the disadvantage that the members elected have no connection with the voters who put them there, as they are chosen from a list drawn up by their party in order of total number of votes for the party. The ordinary voter has no specific elected member to whom he can turn for advice, or complaint, or comment.

Constituency representation has the great advantage that the elected members are responsible to a specific group of voters (of whatever party), and are answerable to them. On the other had, constituency representation makes it possible for a party with a minority of total votes to gain a majority in Parliament, or for a part that draws a considerable number of votes in each constituency to have no representation in Parliament, if it does not gain a majority in any single constituency.

The systems could be combined, for example, by having the voters vote in constituencies, and totalling votes for each party over the whole country. If party A gained 60% of the total votes, it would be given 60% of the seats in Parliament, and those 60% would be the constituencies where they had polled the most votes. In general most of those constituencies would be headed in vote count by the candidate from Party A, but not necessarily so. Party B, with 30% of the total vote, would be given 30% of the seats in Parliament, which may well include some constituencies where it did not head the poll. Similarly, Party C with only 5% of the total vote (a minimum qualifying proportion may be desirable) would have to be given 5% of the seats, some or all of which would probably be constituencies where Party C might have only come second or third. These anomalies can be considered minor, when weighed against the advantage of having a Parliament which is fully representative, and where members have a responsibility to a specific group of voters in one constituency, of whatever party.


J. G. Gie