South Africa: Supreme Court of Appeal

You are here:
SAFLII >>
Databases >>
South Africa: Supreme Court of Appeal >>
2005 >>
[2005] ZASCA 80
| Noteup
| LawCite
Maize Board v Jackson (396/2004) [2005] ZASCA 80; [2006] 3 All SA 511 (SCA); 2005 (6) SA 592 (SCA) (19 September 2005)
Download original files | Links to summary |
Last Updated: 3 December 2005
REPUBLIC OF SOUTH AFRICA
THE SUPREME COURT OF APPEAL
OF SOUTH
AFRICA
Reportable
Case Number : 396 / 04
In the matter between
MAIZE
BOARD APPELLANT
and
JOHN
JACKSON RESPONDENT
Coram : HOWIE P, STREICHER, VAN HEERDEN, PONNAN JJA et
NKABINDE AJA
Date of hearing
: 5 SEPTEMBER 2005
Date of
delivery : 19 SEPTEMBER 2005
SUMMARY
Contracts – simulation – lease and management
agreements - evidence establishing true nature of the transaction one for
the
sale of maize – agreements simulated to conceal that intention to avoid
the payment of Maize Board levies.
___________________________________________________________________
J U D G M E N T
___________________________________________________________________
PONNAN
JA
[1] The dispute in this case turns upon the true nature of two
simultaneously concluded, separate, but interrelated written agreements.
As a
general rule parties to a contract intend it to be exactly what it purports to
be. Not infrequently however, they may endeavour
to conceal its true character.
In such a case, when called upon, a court must give effect to what the
transaction really is and not
what in form it purports to
be.[1]
[2] The appellant,
the Maize Board ('Maize Board'), is a control board contemplated in s 25 of the
Marketing Act 59 of 1958 ('the
Act'), charged with the responsibility of
administering the Summer Grain Scheme ('the
Scheme').[2] From 1944 onwards the
marketing of maize was governed in South Africa by what has been described in
the evidence as a 'single channel
fixed price system'. Simply put, the effect
of that system was that there was a single buyer and seller of all maize in the
country
– the Maize Board. A pre-season announcement by the Minister of
Agriculture ('the Minister') fixed both the producer and consumer
prices of
maize. The advantage of that system, so it was suggested, was that there was
price stability in the market place.
[3] In terms of the Act and the
Scheme, a levy, special levy and general levy were imposed on maize. Those
levies, which were fixed
by the Minister, were payable by a producer of maize to
the Maize Board in respect of maize sold or utilised for any purpose otherwise
than for his own household consumption or to feed his own
animals.[3] During each marketing
season the consumer price was determined by adding the levies to the producer
price.[4] The imposition of the
levies caused unhappiness amongst the consumers and producers of maize, who
sought to regulate their affairs
in such a way as to attempt to circumvent their
levy obligations.[5] The single
channel system came to be replaced during the 1995/6 marketing season with what
was described in the evidence as a free
market system. The free market system,
as the name suggests, permitted a maize producer to sell maize to a willing
purchaser at
a mutually agreed price.
[4] Rainbow Chicken Farms (Pty) Ltd
('Rainbow'), which carries on business as a breeder and producer of broiler
chickens, is, according
to the evidence, the largest consumer of yellow maize in
this country. For each of the production seasons 1992/3, 1993/4 and 1994/5,
Rainbow entered into two written agreements with the respondent, a farmer in the
Bergville area of Kwa Zulu Natal.[6]
In terms of the first, an agreement of lease, the respondent let to Rainbow
certain portions of his farm. In terms of the second,
styled a management
agreement, Rainbow employed the respondent as the manager of its maize farming
operations on the leased land.
Pursuant to those agreements, the respondent
produced and delivered to Rainbow, during the 1993/4, 1994/5 and 1995/6
marketing seasons,
1322.067, 2250 and 1453.936 tons of maize,
respectively.
[5] The Maize Board instituted action against the
respondent in the Pietermaritzburg High Court for payment of levies in
the sum of
R576 439.63, alleging in paragraph 7 of its particulars of claim
that:
'... the lease and management agreements were simulated and were
concluded in their terms with the intention:
7.1 of disguising that the Defendant in fact sold and Rainbow in fact purchased the yellow maize produced on the land; and
7.2 of evading the payment of the levies referred to in paragraph 8 below, on the basis that Rainbow was the "producer" of the crop for its own use and thereby exempt from the said levies;
whereas in truth and in fact
the Defendant was in respect of each such crop the "producer" of it, as defined
in the said Maize Marketing
Scheme and therefore the entity obliged to pay the
levies.'
In dismissing the claim of the Maize Board, Hugo J concluded in the
court below that: ‘the Plaintiff has not succeeded in proving
that the
agreements entered into between the Defendant and Rainbow were not what they
purported to be but that in fact that they
were a simulated agreement of
purchase and sale’. The present appeal is with the leave of this
court.
[6] The argument advanced on behalf of the respondent both before
this court as well as the court below is that Rainbow was feeding
its own
chickens with maize produced on land leased by it. It was accordingly, so the
argument went, utilising the maize 'to feed
its own animals' and was therefore
exempt from liability for payment of levies.
[7] This court recently held
(per Scott JA) in Michau v Maize Board 2003 (6) SA 459 para 4:
'[I]t
has long since been established in cases such as Zandberg v Van Zyl 1910
AD 302, Dadoo Ltd and Others v Krugersdorp Municipal Council 1920 AD 530,
Commissioner of Customs and Excise v Randles, Brothers & Hudson Ltd
1941 AD 369 and more recently affirmed in Erf 3183/1Ladysmith (Pty) Ltd and
Another v Commissioner of Inland Revenue [1996] ZASCA 35; 1996 (3) SA 942 (A) that parties
are free to arrange their affairs so as to remain outside the provisions of a
particular statute. Merely because
those provisions would not have been avoided
had the parties structured their transaction in a different and perhaps more
convenient
way does not render the transaction objectionable. What they may not
do is conceal the true nature of their transaction or in the
words of Innes JA
in Zandberg's case, supra, at 309, "call it by a name, or give it
a shape, intended not to express but to disguise its true nature". In such
event a court
will strip off its ostensible form and give effect to what the
transaction really is. But, while the principle is easy enough to
state in the
abstract, its application in practice may sometimes give rise to considerable
difficulty. Each case will depend upon
its own facts. A Court will seek to
ascertain the true intention of the parties from all the relevant circumstances,
including the
manner in which the contract is implemented. The onus is upon the
party who alleges that the transaction is simulated.'
[8] A manifest
intention to avoid the payment of levies would not, in the absence of anything
else, be sufficient to justify the claim
by the Maize Board that the agreements
were simulated and that the true or real nature of the contractual relationship
between Rainbow
and the respondent was one of purchase and sale. The true
enquiry in a matter such as this is to establish whether the real nature
and the
implementation of these particular contracts is consistent with their ostensible
form. In pursuit of that enquiry one must
strive to ascertain, from all of the
relevant circumstances, the actual meaning of the contracting parties. It
therefore becomes
necessary to examine in greater detail the agreements in
question and the manner in which they were implemented.
[9] The
agreements were signed simultaneously and were plainly interdependent to the
extent that the one would not have been concluded
in the absence of the other.
The parties restricted their own power of subsequent variation by including a
non-variation clause
in each agreement, as well as recording that it constituted
the whole agreement between them.
[10] Clause 6.2 of the Management
Agreement provides:
'Should all the feed grown on the land during the growing
season and delivered by the manager average the minimum yield per hectare
reflected in Schedule I or more Rainbow shall pay to the manager over and
above the basic remuneration a bonus per hectare calculated in accordance with
the formula reflected in Schedule I.'
[11] The formula for the
calculation of the production bonus in Schedule 1 of the agreement was described
by the learned judge a quo
as one that ‘contains some twenty six different
items resulting in a somewhat complex reckoning of such a production
bonus’.
Included in the formula is an item ‘O’ which is
described as ‘Factor’. Neither ‘O’ nor 'Factor'
are
defined elsewhere in the agreement. Nor is any value attributed to either of
them. Moreover, each of the subsequent elements
‘Q’,
‘R’ and ‘S’ in the formula are dependent for their
determination on the value of the undefined
‘Factor O’. Absent a
value for ‘O’, the complex formula is rendered meaningless and can
have offered no assistance
to Rainbow for the determination of the production
bonus due to the respondent.
[12] It is common cause that during the
1994/5 production season the respondent failed by some 256 tons to achieve the
minimum yield
specified in Clause 6.2 read with Schedule 1 and that he therefore
did not qualify for payment of the stipulated bonus. He was nevertheless
paid a
production bonus by Rainbow in the sum of approximately R156 220.
That in the face of the clear wording of
Clause 6.2 that a bonus to be
determined in accordance ‘with the formula reflected in Schedule 1’
was payable only in
the event of the specified minimum yield being achieved or
exceeded. As the minimum yield had not been reached, not only did the
respondent not qualify for payment of the production bonus but the formula for
the determination of the production bonus, did not
find application.
[13] On 21 September 1994 the respondent applied for a loan to the Land
and Agriculture Bank of South Africa. In a statement under
oath in support of
that application, not only did the respondent not disclose the existence of the
lease and management agreements,
which had been in existence since at least the
1992/3 production season, but he asserted that he farmed on his own properties.
A
portion of one of those properties was already at that stage the subject of
the lease agreement. He likewise failed to divulge in
the application under the
heading ‘Any Other Income (Salary etc)’ any of the remuneration,
rental or bonus due to him
in terms of the agreements. That he failed in a
statement under oath to make full disclosure of items that would in all
probability
have enhanced his application is, in the absence of any explanation,
inexplicable.
[14] It was put by counsel for the respondent to the
Maize Board’s witnesses, with reference to an alleged overpayment of
so-called
'fixed costs' by Rainbow to the respondent - ‘I want to tell you
the defendant paid back ... I’m telling you that as
a fact. That will be
his evidence.’ That clearly presaged the respondent being called as a
witness. And yet, although in
a position to do so, he deliberately refrained
from testifying about matters peculiarly within his knowledge or elucidating the
facts.
Should an adverse inference be drawn from his failure to testify as was
urged upon us? Given the particular circumstances of the
litigation, this being
the yardstick to be used, that, it would seem is the most natural inference.
For this is not the kind of
case where a dearth of information would preclude a
decisive inference. Indeed on an analysis of the evidence adduced by the Maize
Board, a reasonable expectation existed that the respondent would testify about
the elusive ‘Factor O’, the payments
he received, his non-disclosure
to the Land Bank, as well as various other aspects that were alluded to by his
counsel during the
cross-examination of the Maize Board’s witnesses. The
inescapable conclusion must therefore be that because of the facts known
to
himself, he could not benefit - and indeed might well have damaged his case - by
testifying. It follows on the facts here present
that the respondent’s
silence must count against him. It would thus be fair to infer that he failed to
disclose the agreements
to the Land Bank because, in truth, they were illusory
and not real.
[15] The provisions of the Management Agreement with regard
to payment were clearly disregarded by Rainbow and the respondent. Properly
construed, the computation and subsequent payment of the production bonus by
Rainbow to the respondent could hardly have occurred
in accordance with the
tenor of the Management Agreement. If the production bonus was not due in terms
of the agreement, why - it
must be asked - was it paid by Rainbow? Two
hypothetical possibilities come to mind. They appear to be exhaustive. First, it
was
a donation; or, secondly, it was payment in terms of some other undisclosed
agreement. Given the nature of the relationship between
Rainbow and the
respondent, it could hardly have been the first - commercial reality excludes
that possibility. It is to the second
that one must look, as it, inherently,
sounds the more likely and must in my view be the true explanation. Support for
the existence
of an undisclosed agreement is to be found in what was put by the
respondent’s counsel to one of the Maize Board’s witnesses.
Of
‘Factor O’ he stated ‘[it] ... is an agreed factor ... It is
not in the contracts, but it’s an agreed
factor.’
[16] The
payment, coupled with the established fact of delivery of maize by the
respondent to Rainbow, leads inexorably to the conclusion
that the undisclosed
agreement was indeed one of purchase and sale of maize. I accordingly conclude
that the underlying and disguised
transaction was one for the purchase and sale
of maize and that the agreements were simulated to conceal that intention.
[17] Ultimately what the parties achieved is that Rainbow paid less and
the respondent received more than would have been the case
had the sale been
conducted under the auspices of the Maize Board. I am satisfied on all of the
aforegoing that the Maize Board
discharged the onus of establishing that the
true nature of the transaction between Rainbow and the respondent was the
purchase by
the former of the latter’s maize. The respondent is thus
liable to the Maize Board for payment of levies. It follows that
the appeal must
succeed.
[18] In the result the following order is made:
1 The appeal succeeds with costs, such costs to include the costs of two counsel.
2 The order of the court below is set aside and replaced with the following:
'1 Judgment is granted in favour of the Plaintiff for the payment of
R576 439.63 together with interest thereon at 15.5% per annum from the dates when the levies ought to have been paid to date of payment.
2 The Defendant is ordered to pay the costs of the action, including the costs of two counsel and Professor Hammes and Mr Smith are declared to have been necessary witnesses.'
V M PONNAN
JUDGE OF APPEAL
CONCURRING:
HOWIE
P
STREICHER JA
VAN HEERDEN JA
NKABINDE
AJA
[1] Zandberg v Van Zyl 1910
AD 302 at 309.
[2] Although the Act
has since been repealed, the Maize Board continues to exist by virtue of s 27(2)
of the Marketing of Agricultural Products Act 47 of 1996. The Summer Grain
Scheme was established in 1979 in terms of s 14(1)(a) of the Act (see Michau
v Maize Board 2003 (6) SA 459 (SCA) para
3).
[3] Although the earlier
proclamations referred to 'farming operations' instead of 'feed his own
animals', nothing, it would appear,
turns on
that.
[4] A production (or growing)
season spanned the period 1st October to 30th September
and the corresponding marketing season the period 1st May to
30th September of the succeeding year. Thus maize produced during
the 1992/3 production season (1st October 1992 –
30th September 1993) would be marketed in the 1993/4 marketing season
(1st May 1993 – 30th April
1994).
[5] On 21 May 1987 Rainbow
Chicken Farms (Pty) Ltd wrote to the Maize Board: ‘We now find that
various schemes to bypass the summer grain scheme are in operation and every
week we are approached by producers
to do the same. We cannot continue to
support the maize industry and allow our competitors to steal a march on
us.’.
[6] The only
agreements produced in the court below related to the 1994/5 production season.
Of that the court below stated: ‘The
parties have however only been able
to trace the contracts for the 1994/1995 production season. The Court has been
asked to infer
that the contracts for the previous two production seasons were
in similar terms with only the figures, areas and amounts changing
from year to
year. For the purposes of this judgment I am prepared to make that assumption.'